Highlights
- •Many policy debates center on the idea that the supply side is capturing too much of the value of the medical innovation that they generate.
- •We analyze a large data set with > 9000 cost-effectiveness measures for various interventions and find that a large share of the value of medical innovation accrues to patients on the demand side given that the revenue to innovators is often far less than the patient’s value of these medical innovations.
- •Our research finds that a large share of the value of medical innovation accrues to patients on the demand side given that the revenue to innovators is often far less than the patient’s value of these medical innovations.
Abstract
Objectives
This article provides systematic evidence on the share of the value of health generated
by drugs and other healthcare goods and services that accrue to patients on the demand
side versus the manufacturers on the supply side.
Methods
We exploit a large data set with > 9000 cost-effectiveness measures for various interventions,
which we convert into measures of the shares of the value of improved health appropriated
by the supply side using literature estimates of how patients value gains in health.
Results
We find that if patients value a quality-adjusted life-year at $450 000 the median
share appropriated for drugs on the supply side is approximately 6% and has declined
at 0.1% per year between 1997 and 2019. This compares with other healthcare interventions,
such as screenings or medical procedures, which have a median value of 9% but decline
at 0.3% per year over the same period. If patients value a quality-adjusted life-year
at $150 000, the median share appropriated for drugs and other healthcare interventions
on the supply side is approximately 18% and 27%, respectively. Our estimates of appropriations
are upper bounds, partly due to QALYs not capturing full producer value.
Conclusions
Many policy debates center on the idea that the supply side is capturing too much
of the value of the medical innovation that they generate. We find that, for these
interventions, a large share of the value of medical innovation accrues to patients
on the demand side given that the revenue to innovators is often far less than the
patient’s value of these medical innovations.
Keywords
To read this article in full you will need to make a payment
Purchase one-time access:
Academic & Personal: 24 hour online accessCorporate R&D Professionals: 24 hour online accessOne-time access price info
- For academic or personal research use, select 'Academic and Personal'
- For corporate R&D use, select 'Corporate R&D Professionals'
Subscribe:
Subscribe to Value in HealthAlready a print subscriber? Claim online access
Already an online subscriber? Sign in
Register: Create an account
Institutional Access: Sign in to ScienceDirect
References
- Who benefits from new medical technologies? Estimates of consumer and producer surpluses for HIV/AIDS drugs.Forum Health Econ Policy. 2006; 9: 1-33
- Dividing the benefits from medical breakthroughs.The Milken Rev. 2006; 1: 46-56
- An economic evaluation of the war on cancer.J Health Econ. 2010; 29: 333-346
- The large social value resulting from use of statins warrants steps to improve adherence and broaden treatment.Health Aff (Millwood). 2012; 31: 2276-2285
- Appropriating the returns from investments in R&D capital.in: European Industrial Restructuring in the 1990s. Palgrave Macmillan, London, United Kingdom1992: 331-356
- Social and private rates of return from industrial innovations.Q J Econ. 1977; 91: 221-240
- Schumpeterian profits in the American economy: theory and measurement. NBER Working Paper.https://www.nber.org/papers/w10433Date accessed: September 10, 2022
- How does technological change affect quality-adjusted prices in health care? Systematic evidence from thousands of innovations.Am J Health Econ. 2018; 4: 433-453
- Are pharmaceuticals cost-effective? A review of the evidence.Health Aff (Millwood). 2000; 19: 92-109
- Are medical care prices still declining? A re-examination based on cost-effectiveness studies.Econometrica. 2022; 90: 859-886
- The impact of recent generic drug price policies on pharmaceutical innovation: a theoretical rationale and proposal of a method supporting innovation in areas of unmet medical need.Value Health. 2013; 16: A492
- Best estimate selection bias in the value of a statistical life.J Benefit Cost Anal. 2018; 9: 205-246
- Valuing reductions in fatal illness risks: implications of recent research.Health Econ. 2016; 25: 1039-1052
- The role of publication selection bias in estimates of the value of a statistical life.Am J Health Econ. 2015; 1: 27-52
- The value of a statistical life: a critical review of market estimates throughout the world.J Risk Uncertainty. 2003; 27: 5-76
- Anchoring biases in international estimates of the value of a statistical life.J Risk Uncertainty. 2017; 54: 103-128
- EPA guidelines for regulatory impact analysis. University Library of Munich.https://ideas.repec.org/p/wpa/wuwpot/9602003.htmlDate accessed: September 10, 2022
- Mortality risk valuation. Environmental Protection Agency.https://www.epa.gov/environmental-economics/mortality-risk-valuation#Date accessed: September 10, 2022
- Guidance on treatment of the economic value of a statistical life (VSL) in U.S. Department of Transportation analyses – 2015 adjustment. US Department of Transportation.https://perma.cc/Y8DU-XV9QDate accessed: September 10, 2022
- Drug pricing investigation, majority staff report. U.S. House of Representatives Committee on Oversight and Reform.https://oversight.house.gov/sites/democrats.oversight.house.gov/files/DRUG%20PRICING%20REPORT%20WITH%20APPENDIX%20v3.pdfDate accessed: November 21, 2022
Article info
Publication history
Published online: December 08, 2022
Accepted:
December 1,
2022
Publication stage
In Press Corrected ProofIdentification
Copyright
© 2023 International Society for Pharmacoeconomics and Outcomes Research, Inc. Published by Elsevier Inc.